Lecture_08_Intertemporal_Choice

Lecture_08_Intertemp - Lecture 8 Intertemporal Choice Outline 1 Introduction 2 Intertemporal Consumption Choice c 2008 Jerey A Miron 2 Comparative

Info iconThis preview shows pages 1–3. Sign up to view the full content.

View Full Document Right Arrow Icon
Lecture 8: Intertemporal Choice c 2008 Je/rey A. Miron Outline 1. Introduction 2. Intertemporal Consumption Choice 2. Comparative Statics: Borrowers versus Lenders 3. The Interest Rate and Savings 4. Real versus Nominal Interest Rates 1 Introduction We next want to examine an application of the consumer choice model to a situation where the consumer chooses consumption today versus consumption tomorrow. This application provides a number of useful insights, some of them similar to insights from the labor supply application. The intertemporal choice model is also the foundation for a large fraction of We will mention a few of courses. In addition, this material provides a good illustration and review of the techniques we have developed so far. Consider a consumer who thinks about how much to consume of some composite good in each of two periods: ( c 1 ; c 2 ) The consumer receives an endowment of consumption goods (manna from heaven) in each period: ( ! 1 ; ! 2 ) . 1
Background image of page 1

Info iconThis preview has intentionally blurred sections. Sign up to view the full version.

View Full DocumentRight Arrow Icon
Essentially, we want to understand what factors determine how much the consumer chooses to consume this period versus next period. In all the examples below, we assume the consumer has a utility function that depends on the amount of consumption this period and the amount of consumption next period: u ( c 1 ; c 2 ) . This is the most general utility function we could specify for this situation. Often it is useful to choose a more restricted utility function; for example, we might want to make u () additively separable in consumption today versus consumption tomorrow: u ( c 1 ; c 2 ) = v ( c 1 ) + w ( c 2 ) . In many cases, we impose a further restriction and write u ( c 1 ; c 2 ) = v ( c 1 ) + ( c 2 ) 0 1 . This says that the consumer has the same within period utility function in each period, but that viewed from this period, getting consumption next period is not as good as getting consumption now; the consumer discounts future consumption at the rate . Thus, is known as the discount factor. 2 Intertemporal Consumption Choice is non-storable; for example, the good might be food that only lasts one period and then becomes inedible. In addition, we assume that no asset markets exist, so the consumer cannot borrow or lend or buy stocks or own anything that has durable value between periods 1 and 2. In this case, what does the budget set look like?
Background image of page 2
Image of page 3
This is the end of the preview. Sign up to access the rest of the document.

This note was uploaded on 09/16/2009 for the course ECONOMICS 1010A taught by Professor Jeffreya.miron during the Fall '09 term at Harvard.

Page1 / 17

Lecture_08_Intertemp - Lecture 8 Intertemporal Choice Outline 1 Introduction 2 Intertemporal Consumption Choice c 2008 Jerey A Miron 2 Comparative

This preview shows document pages 1 - 3. Sign up to view the full document.

View Full Document Right Arrow Icon
Ask a homework question - tutors are online