Lecture31-32

Lecture31-32 - 123 Lectures 31 & 32 - Functional form...

Info iconThis preview shows pages 1–3. Sign up to view the full content.

View Full Document Right Arrow Icon
123 Lectures 31 & 32 - Functional form 1) The next topic we will discuss concerns the functional form of the regression equation. That is, do the variables enter in linear form, as squares, logs, etc. . Once again, we should allow theory to determine this as far as possible. Your text gives you the impression that this can almost always be accomplished. Unfortunately, this is not so! Most economic theories tell you only the sign that should be on the coefficient. (For instance, in macro you learned that consumption is a positive function of income, but the theory said nothing about whether income should be squared, or enter as a log, etc.). Thus, here is a place where art plays an important role. It would be better if theory did indicate the form of the variables, unfortunately this is not always the case. We will begin with a discussion of the interpretation and reliability of the constant term . We have seen that there are 2 reasons for not placing much confidence in the estimate of the constant term. These are: a) We do not have sample values close to the origin , and hence cannot get an accurate estimate for the intercept. b) The constant term adjusts to correct for the fact that the expected value of the error term may not be equal to 0 , as is required by the classical assumptions. Thus the estimate we get for the constant term may not be the true constant, reflecting this adjustment. The interpretation of the constant is that it tells us the value of the dependent variable when the independent variables take on the value = 0. Some economic theories may imply that the constant should be equal to 0. For instance, in a production function we would normally assume that if the amount of labor used is equal to 0, then output will also be equal to 0, implying that the intercept is equal to 0. The question then arises as to whether we should force the constant to be equal to 0 when doing the regression. This is called ‘suppressing the constant’. The answer is that we should not do this. The following picture helps to understand why: $ Y $ Y with constant 0 Y X
Background image of page 1

Info iconThis preview has intentionally blurred sections. Sign up to view the full version.

View Full DocumentRight Arrow Icon
124 If we force the constant to be equal to 0 then we are estimating the regression line that goes through the origin. Given the sample we actually have, this clearly increases the size of the slope estimate we would have obtained had we not suppressed the constant. Thus, our t-values will increase. The problem here is really just a version of (a) above. Although theory tells us that the function should go through the origin, the sample we have is not close enough to the origin to let us know what the shape of the function appears like in that region. In the sample we actually have we obtain the regression equation with the positive intercept. If the theory is true, then we must have a non-linear relationship. But we do not have sample values that enable us to estimate what the nonlinear relation looks like. Hence, we will get a more accurate representation of the true relationship if we estimate within the sample we have and don't suppress the constant, even though theory says the constant = 0.
Background image of page 2
Image of page 3
This is the end of the preview. Sign up to access the rest of the document.

This note was uploaded on 03/03/2011 for the course ECO 230 taught by Professor Yongjinpark during the Spring '11 term at Conn College.

Page1 / 9

Lecture31-32 - 123 Lectures 31 & 32 - Functional form...

This preview shows document pages 1 - 3. Sign up to view the full document.

View Full Document Right Arrow Icon
Ask a homework question - tutors are online