section8 (1)

section8 (1) - Continuous Time Finance Notes Spring 2004...

Info iconThis preview shows pages 1–2. Sign up to view the full content.

View Full Document Right Arrow Icon
Continuous Time Finance Notes, Spring 2004 – Section 8, March 24, 2004 Notes by Robert V. Kohn, Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences. For use in connec- tion with the NYU course Continuous Time Finance. This section begins by wrapping up our discussion of HJM – discussing its strengths and weaknesses. Then we turn to the “Libor Market Model” – which though relatively new is rapidly becoming the method of choice for many purposes. Our discussion of the Libor Market Model follows Hull’s treatment (Section 24.3 of the 5th edition). ***************** Some comments on the HJM approach to interest rate modelling: HJM is a “framework” not a “model” . When modeling equity-based derivatives, our usual framework is to assume the underlying solves a diffusion process ds = μ ( s, t ) dt + σ ( s, t ) dw . The market is complete for any choice of the functions μ ( s, t ) and σ ( s, t ) (with some minor restrictions, for example σ ( s, t ) > 0). But what to choose for μ and σ ? The choice of μ is of course irrelevant for option pricing, because under the risk-neutral measure the underlying satisfies ds = r dt + σ ( s, t ) dw . But the choice of σ is crucial. We commonly choose σ ( s, t ) = σ 0 s with σ 0 constant, i.e. we commonly assume the underlying has lognor- mal dynamics. (This is not the only possibility; in a week or two we’ll discuss “local vol” models, i.e. the idea of using the skew/smile of implied volatilities to infer an appropriate choice of σ ( s, t ).) The situation with HJM is analogous. For one-factor HJM, the framework is d t f ( t, T ) = α ( t, T ) dt + σ ( t, T ) dw . Working under the risk-neutral measure (i.e. assuming w is a Brownian motion in the risk-neutral measure) the drift α is completely specified by σ . The choice of σ is again crucial. It is no longer so obvious how to choose it; we saw how to choose σ ( t, T ) to get either Ho-Lee or Hull-White. But many other choices are possible. Calibration to data is not easy, because when σ is not deterministic (e.g. if it depends explicitly on f ( t, T )) we have no exact pricing formulas. It is natural to suppose σ is a function of f as well as t and T . Indeed, if σ is a deterministic function of t and T then f ( t, T ) is Gaussian, so there is a positive probability that it is negative. We tolerated this in Hull-White, and one often tolerates it in HJM for the same reason – namely analytical tractability of the model. However a model that permits negative interest rates cannot be the last word. Amongst short-rate models the simplest way to keep the short rate positive is to use a state-dependent volatility: for example the Cox-Ingersoll-Ross model assumes dr = ( θ ( t ) - ar ) dt + σ 0 r dw (compare this to Hull-White: dr = ( θ ( t ) - ar ) dt + σ 0 dw ). Our discussion of HJM (in particular: our explanation how the volatility determines the drift) did not assume σ was deterministic. It applies with no change if, for example, σ has the form
Background image of page 1

Info iconThis preview has intentionally blurred sections. Sign up to view the full version.

View Full DocumentRight Arrow Icon
Image of page 2
This is the end of the preview. Sign up to access the rest of the document.

This note was uploaded on 01/02/2012 for the course FINANCE 347 taught by Professor Bayou during the Fall '11 term at NYU.

Page1 / 6

section8 (1) - Continuous Time Finance Notes Spring 2004...

This preview shows document pages 1 - 2. Sign up to view the full document.

View Full Document Right Arrow Icon
Ask a homework question - tutors are online