lecture15_slides

lecture15_slides - Econ 121. Intermediate Microeconomics....

Info iconThis preview shows page 1. Sign up to view the full content.

View Full Document Right Arrow Icon
This is the end of the preview. Sign up to access the rest of the document.

Unformatted text preview: Econ 121. Intermediate Microeconomics. Eduardo Faingold Yale University Lecture 15 Outline of the course I. Introduction II. Individual choice III. Competitive markets IV. Market failure Outline of the course I. Introduction II. Individual choice III. Competitive markets Partial equilibrium (Ch. 16) Exchange economies (Ch. 31) Production (Ch. 1823) IV. Market failure Production Technological constraints of a firm represented by a production set in input-output space. Consider the one input one output case. Boundary of production set is y D f .x/; where the function f is called the production function. Production Now consider the two input one output case. Production function: y D f .x1; x2/; where y is the output level, and x1 and x2 are the input levels. Inputs 1 and 2 are sometimes called production factors. Production N Isoquants: Set of input combinations .x1; x2/ with f .x1; x2/ D y , for given y. N Three leading examples a b Cobb-Douglas: f .x1; x2 / D Ax1 x2 . Perfect complements: f .x1; x2/ D minfx1; x2g. Perfect substitutes: f .x1; x2/ D ax1 C bx2. Standard assumptions on technology Monotonicity: production function f .x1; x2/ is increasing in x1 and x2 Convexity: isoquants are convex Marginal product. Technical Rate of Substitution. Consider two input model. Marginal product of factor 1: MP1.x1 ; x2 / D and analogously for factor 2. Technical rate of substitution: @f .x1 ; x2 /; @x1 TRS.x1; x2/ D slope of the isoquant that passes through .x1; x2/ MP1.x1 ; x2/ MP2.x1 ; x2/ Diminishing MP and TRS Two standard properties of technologies: Law of Diminishing MP: MP1 decreases in x1 for fixed x2, and likewise for MP2. Diminishing TRS: jTRSj decreases in x1 along isoquant. Long-run vs. short-run Within a certain fixed period of time it might be infeasible to change some production factors. y D f .x1; x2/ N with x2 fixed. This is the short run. N Eventually, all factors can change. This is the long run. Returns to scale When we talked about the law of diminishing MP, we consider the change in MP1 due to a change in x1 holding x2 fixed. Now we are going to consider joint changes in x1 and x2. If we double all inputs, does output double, less than double or more than double? Returns to scale Constant returns to scale: for all t > 1, f .tx1; tx2 / D tf .x1; x2/ Increasing returns to scale: for all t > 1, f .tx1; tx2 / > tf .x1; x2/ Decreasing returns to scale: for all t > 1, f .tx1; tx2 / < tf .x1; x2/ Profit maximization One output y , two inputs x1 and x2. A competitive firm takes prices p , w1 and w2 as given and solves: .y;x1 ;x2 / max py w1x1 w2x2 subj. to y D f .x1; x2/ or, equivalently, .x1 ;x2 / max pf .x1; x2/ w1x1 w2x2: Profit maximization First-order conditions: MP1.x1; x2/ D w1=p MP2.x1; x2/ D w2=p; which is TRS.x1; x2/ D (Note the analogy with consumer theory.) w1 : w2 This characterization is valid whenever isoquants are smooth and convex and solution is interior (i.e., both x1 and x2 are positive). Constant returns implies zero profits If profits were not zero, by doubling input one could double the profit. If initial profit were positive, firm could not be choosing an input combination that maximizes its profits! Let us see this more formally.... At the optimum, profit is ... D pf .x1 ; x2 / w1x1 w2x2 ; * where .x1 ; x2 / is the profit-maximizing combination of inputs. Using the constant returns to scale assumption, doubling the inputs yields a profit of pf .2x1 ; 2x2 / 2w1x1 2w2x2 D 2...; which is strictly greater than ..., unless ... D 0. Hence, ... must be zero, otherwise .x1 ; x2 / would not be profit-maximizing. Cobb-douglas example a b Technology: y D f .x1; x2/ D x1 x2 . FOC: a b ax1 1x2 a b bx1 x2 1 w1 D MP1.x1; x2/ D p w2 D MP2.x1; x2/ D p look up the algebra in the textbook A bit of algebra (see appendix of Chapter 19) yields aCb 1 a b yDp a w1 a 1 a b b w2 b 1 a b Notice that this is not well defined for a C b D 1 (constant returns). Cost minimization For each output level y , a competitive firm must choose a combination of inputs to minimize cost subject to the constraint that the combination of inputs yields output y . Cost minimization: .x1 ;x2 / min w1x1 C w2x2 subj. to f .x1; x2/ D y The value of w1x1 C w2x2 at the minimum is denoted c.y/ and it is called the cost function. Cost minimization Profit maximization then becomes: max py y 0 c.y/ with first-order condition: p D c 0.y/ for interior solutions y > 0. M C.y/; Cost minimization Now let c.y/ D cv .y/ C F , where F > 0 is the fixed cost and cv is the variable cost, i.e., cv .0/ D 0. The average cost is defined as AC.y/ D c.y/=y , and the average variable cost is AV C.y/ D cv .y/=y . The marginal cost curve intersects the average cost and the average variable cost curves at their minima. In fact, if y minimizes AC then 0 D AC 0.y / D M C.y /y c.y / y 2 ) M C.y / D c.y /=y D AC.y /; and analogously for AV C . Supply curve The (inverse) supply curve is obtained from the first-order condition p D M C.y/; with two exceptions. First, the firm would never choose an output level y with p D M C.y/ when M C is decreasing around y . Otherwise, by increasing y a little bit it would increase profits. Second, the firm will choose a positive output level y with p D M C.y/ only if this yields higher profits than producing zero: py cv .y/ F F ) p AV C.y/: In sum, the inverse supply curve is the increasing portion of the marginal cost curve that lies above the average cost curve. inverse supply curve ...
View Full Document

Ask a homework question - tutors are online