Experience is, in fact, consistent with our theory. When the patent on a drug expires, other companies quickly
enter and begin selling so-called generic products that are chemically identical to the former monopolist's
brand-name product. And just as our analysis predicts, the price of the competitively produced generic drug is
well below the price that the monopolist was charging.
Figure 6The Market for Drugs
When a patent gives a firm a monopoly over the sale of a drug, the firm charges the monopoly price, which is
well above the marginal cost of making the drug. When the patent on a drug runs out, new firms enter the
market, making it more competitive. As a result, the price falls from the monopoly price to marginal cost.

The expiration of a patent, however, does not cause the monopolist to lose all its market power. Some
consumers remain loyal to the brand-name drug, perhaps out of fear that the new generic drugs are not actually
the same as the drug they have been using for years. As a result, the former monopolist can continue to charge a
price above the price charged by its new competitors.
For example, one of the most widely used antidepressants is the drug fluoxetine, which is taken by millions of
Americans. Because the patent on this drug expired in 2001, a consumer today has the choice between the
original drug, sold under the brand name Prozac, and a generic version of the same medicine. Prozac sells for
about three times the price of generic fluoxetine. This price differential can persist because some consumers are
not convinced that the two pills are perfect substitutes.
15-3
The Welfare Cost Of Monopolies
Is monopoly a good way to organize a market? We have seen that a monopoly, in contrast to a competitive firm,
charges a price above marginal cost. From the standpoint of consumers, this high price makes monopoly
undesirable. At the same time, however, the monopoly is earning profit from charging this high price. From the
standpoint of the owners of the firm, the high price makes monopoly very desirable. Is it possible that the
benefits to the firm's owners exceed the costs imposed on consumers, making monopoly desirable from the
standpoint of society as a whole?
We can answer this question using the tools of welfare economics. Recall from Chapter 7 that total surplus
measures the economic well-being of buyers and sellers in a market. Total surplus is the sum of consumer
surplus and producer surplus. Consumer surplus is consumers' willingness to pay for a good minus the amount
they actually pay for it. Producer surplus is the amount producers receive for a good minus their costs of
producing it. In this case, there is a single producer—the monopolist.
You can probably guess the result of this analysis. In Chapter 7, we concluded that the equilibrium of supply
and demand in a competitive market is not only a natural outcome but also a desirable one. The invisible hand
of the market leads to an allocation of resources that makes total surplus as large as it can be. Because a
monopoly leads to an allocation of resources different from that in a competitive market, the outcome must, in
some way, fail to maximize total economic well-being.


You've reached the end of your free preview.
Want to read all 28 pages?